Political Rents of European Farmers in the Sustainable Development Paradigm. International, national and regional perspective
Abstract
To make a summary of a book that contains so many different threads is no
easy task. One should, on the one hand, refer to its conceptual contribution to the
paradigm of sustainable agriculture, and on the other hand, consider the conclusions
drawn from the studies conducted at international, national and regional level. It is
clear that changing the paradigm of agricultural development from an industrial to a
sustainable one will be neither easy nor quick. Agriculture must satisfy the demand
for food products while lowering the pressure on the environment, providing for
technological and biological progress, meeting the need to ensure a secure supply of
food, and ensuring global economic, social and environmental rationality.
The discussion in this book has concentrated chiefly on the last two questions.
This is because certain dimensions of environmental and social rationality have so
far been poorly researched. Environmental rationality means not only protecting the
natural environment and reducing the pressure placed on it by agricultural production.
The authors have pointed out that the assumption of an intrinsic value of land changes
the expected productivity of capital in the sectors which utilise that production factor,
namely in agriculture. This has far-reaching theoretical and practical consequences.
The statistical data that have been presented demonstrate that utilities are discounted
in Polish land prices to a much greater degree than would result from the agricultural
functions of land. A similar situation is found in other EU countries. Where does this
excess value of land come from? It is undoubtedly a result of the expectations of
political rents, of speculative motives, and also of non-agricultural amenities provided
by land. However, it is hard to determine the proportions of these factors. Moreover,
new utilities of land have the nature of public goods, which further complicates the
problem of seeking a market equilibrium. Similarly, recognition of the fact of the
absolute and relative deprivation of farmers in the long term changes the balance of
intersectoral flows, because it means a drainage of surplus from agriculture to other
branches of agribusiness. This drainage is understood as a permanent mechanism by
which economic rent flows out of agriculture as a result of market imperfections, in
particular the flexible prices of agricultural products. More space should be given to
studies of this problem in the world literature.
135 Poznan University of Economics and Business, anna.matuszczak@ue.poznan.pl
Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture 239
The second thread of the theoretical considerations relates to the problem of
whether the concept of political rent, as found in the literature, fits the processes
taking place in European agriculture. A review of the literature on rent seeking
suggests that these theories provide only a partial explanation of the level of
political rents and lobbying actions in European agriculture. Although there is a vast
theoretical literature on rent seeking and collective action at global level, there is not
much empirical work done with regard to these problems relating to the Common
Agricultural Policy. Particularly problematic is the question of measuring political
rents in particular EU member states. It has been found that, on a global level, it
is European agriculture that best meets the criteria of viability and sustainability.
Viewed against the backdrop of global agriculture, it is economically effective (in
the institutional conditions guaranteed by the CAP), satisfies a variety of economic
and social needs, and is developing in a way that reduces the burden on the
environment. In 2012, based on the results of social consultations, the European
Commission published a strategy and plan of action relating to the bioeconomy in
Europe. The strategy creates a cohesive framework for a comprehensive approach to
the solution of complex social problems (challenges) in Europe and worldwide. The
measures undertaken with respect to the bioeconomy are focused on three pillars:
investment in research, innovations and skills; strengthening the impact of the policy
and engagement of interested parties; and strengthening competitiveness in sectors
of the bioeconomy. The bioeconomy strategy represents an important step towards
solving contemporary economic and social problems. The model of the development
of agriculture in the EU can thus be considered an appropriate path to be followed
in relatively densely populated countries, in which food producing area per capita
is small. However, does this model require institutional support and the payment of
political rents? The question arises as to whether these are in fact political rents, if
in return society receives a package of specified benefits, and there is a net increase
in social well-being.
Empirical analyses have shown that up to the mid 1980s the level of support for
agriculture in the EU (measured by the NRA indicator) was constantly increasing. The
decline in support in subsequent years was maintained by payments of the decoupled
type. Based on NRA values it can be concluded that nominal support in 2011 was
at a level comparable to that recorded prior to the creation of an organisation of
agricultural markets, that is, before 1962. This means that the CAP is distorting
world prices to an ever smaller degree, and agricultural producers are losing their
competitive advantages (although to differing extents). An important observation
is the fact that, although the CAP applies to all member states, the level of support
varies between those countries. In 2005-2011 it was the highest in Ireland, Slovenia,
Poland, Belgium and the UK, and the lowest in Italy and Bulgaria. This observation
240 Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture
is confirmed by a second indicator constructed for the purposes of this research
by the authors of Chapter 2.3 – the Farm Receipts Gap Estimate (FRGE). Despite
the fact that in principle agricultural policy has a universal application, the amount
of financial support given to agricultural producers measured as a percentage of
gross farm receipts is not uniform between countries, with differences as high as 17
percentage points in 2012136 (cf. Table 2.4.). We should add that, according to the
OECD, the value of the PSE for the whole of the European Union is 22.6% (of gross
receipts). The differences between the PSE and the FRGE result partly from the
methodology used for calculation. Most importantly, however, the FRGE shows how
little uniformity there is across the EU in terms of support for agricultural producers
in different countries. The differences are even more marked when we consider the
contribution of pure political rent137 to the revenue of producers in various countries.
In the Netherlands this contribution is just 4.3%, while for Ireland it is 25.8%
(although the highest value, 28.7%, is recorded in Finland; cf. Table 3.12.). These
data also demonstrate one more thing: that the PSE should not be used as a measure
of political rents, because it significantly overstates them. The mechanisms shaping
the structure of transfers in the selected countries also exhibited clear differences.
This applies in particular to the two main streams of transfers: from taxpayers to
producers and from consumers to producers. There has also been a gradual change in
the structure of support, away from consumer transfers towards taxpayer transfers.
This has resulted both from changes taking place in the global economy and the rise
in prices of agricultural products, as well as from transformations in agriculture’s
role in the economy.
A key part of the book proved to be Part 3, which presents the concept and the
effects of long-term surplus drainage from agriculture under the various support
models applied in the EU as regards equivalent payments (for specific public goods)
and the different models for the taxation of agriculture. The analysis leads to what are
called pure political rents, being what remains when the value of the aforementioned
flows (drainage and net subsidies for public goods) is deducted from the sum of CAP
subsidies. It should be noted that only rents calculated in this way meet the definition
of political rent found in the public choice theory.
Another important thread in this discussion concerns price fluctuations and
their consequences. Agriculture is characterised by a high variability of prices in
particular markets, which leads to adjustments of supply. This reaction is not always
as described by neo-classical concepts – the spider’s web and King’s effects. Farmers’
expectations in different countries may be more or less adaptive, and are sometimes
136 From 19.99% in the Netherlands to 36.96% in Ireland.
137 After adjusting the support by that part the receipt of which is conditional on the supply of
specified public goods, and by the value of long-term drainage resulting from market failures.
Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture 241
rational. This depends on the degree of horizontal and vertical integration of sale
channels, and on access to information. This price variability leads to unexpected
flows of economic surplus into and out of agriculture, and in the authors’ view, this
produces a drainage effect in the long term. In response, there is a fluctuation in
economic activity and in the economic situation in agriculture. This process is not
uniform, however, and varies between different EU countries, as the authors observe.
They propose an economic indicator based on surplus flows as a result of price
fluctuations, based on an input-output table. The largest fluctuations were recorded
in such countries as Germany, Denmark, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Estonia
and Lithuania. At the other extreme (with the smallest amplitudes of variation) are
Portugal, Greece, Cyprus and Malta. At the same time, the value of the computed
indicator determined the changes in farms’ output and receipts, although in some
countries this was a concurrent response, while in others it was delayed. This partly
confirms the hypothesis that the outflow of economic rent from agriculture means
a drop in productive activity, and vice versa (in some cases, however, such as in
Poland, the response was delayed – recalling the spider’s web theory). It was also
shown that the relationship between the economic indicator and the production of
agricultural raw materials differs between countries. In Germany, for example, the
variation in output as a response to price changes is relatively low. Even in the most
difficult period for agriculture (2009) production fell there by just 1%, compared
with 15% in Portugal and as much as 30% in Poland, despite a smaller drop in the
economic indicator. The authors believe this to be a result of the different agrarian
structure, scale and technology of production, differences in the functioning of
market institutions (integrative links, contracting systems), and the reactions of the
producers themselves to the situation. To sum up, drawing conclusions about the
general economic situation based on flows of economic rents is an atypical approach,
but one that can identify the causes of variation in the productive activity on farms
and help compare the scale of such variation between countries. This approach may
also be a useful analytical tool for agricultural policy, which becomes particularly
important in conditions of the intensification of processes of globalisation.
In generalising the conclusions drawn from the analysis of the structure of CAP
support in selected EU countries, three different models were identified138. Only
138 The structure of support is described based on the contribution of the following variables
to total variable subsidies: X1 – the value of payments for public goods, being the sum of set-aside,
agri-environmental and less favoured area payments and other subsidies for the development of
rural areas; X2 – the value of subsidies for plant and animal production (the sum of other payments
to plant and animal production plus the balance of subsidy and penalties for milk production,
subsidy for other cattle production and subsidy for sheep and goat production); X3 – the value of
single farm and area payments; X4 – the value of subsidies for indirect consumption; X5 – the
value of investment subsidies.
242 Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture
two of them – model A (dominated by single farm and area payments, and with
payments for the supply of public goods making up 17% of the total) and model C
(combining different mechanisms of support for farms, with the highest contribution
from payments for public goods, 33%) – were in accordance with the development
priorities of the European agricultural model as defined in the new programming
period of 2014-2020. These operated throughout most of the area of the EU in 2012,
particularly in the new member states (cf. Figure 3.3.). Nonetheless, in most regions
of the “old” EU-15 member states, the model in operation in 2012 was model B,
oriented exclusively towards direct payments, which are treated as a substitute
for support for production and produce a relatively weak stimulus for sustainable
development. Further calculations showed that these countries receive more than
80% of the pure political rents derived from the CAP.
There is also a large variation between EU countries as regards agricultural
income. The tax systems applied to agriculture, however, are very similar (with
certain exceptions, such as the case of Poland). They incorporate taxes on income,
assets and consumption (VAT). The Polish system is different in that it does not
include a tax on income from agricultural production. Based on an evaluation of the
tax systems applied to agriculture in selected EU countries, it is possible to identify
countries having the most restrictive tax policies towards agriculture (Belgium,
Portugal, Ireland, Spain) and those where such policies are less restrictive (the UK,
Germany, Italy, the Netherlands).
Taking account of the long-term surplus drainage from agriculture and the net
equivalent subsidies (in exchange for specific actions relating to public goods), an
estimate was made of the value of “pure” political rents for individual countries of
the EU-27. The analysis carried out here points to the conclusion that agricultural
interventionism in the EU requires a special conceptual approach, since it is not
sufficient to simply treat all subsidies as political rents. The new approach proposed
by the authors is necessary, as it provides an indication of how to improve the
effectiveness of allocation of support for agriculture in individual EU countries.
Quantification of the political rent in agriculture enables a more rational and socially
appropriate distribution of assistance from the CAP in accordance with the goals
set for agricultural policy in the new financial framework after 2014. Although the
division of payment envelopes between member states has already been decided,
since 2014 the CAP has gained flexibility in terms of the structure of both pillars
and transfers between them. These matters remain in the hands of the governments
of member states.
Another issue is the aforementioned contribution of political rents to the gross
receipts from agriculture in a given country (cf. Tables 3.12. and 3.13.). On average
in the EU-27 this contribution is 13.63%, and although in the EU-12 it is slightly
Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture 243
higher, and in the EU-15 somewhat lower than average, there are countries in which
that value is exceeded almost twofold. Redefinition is required as regards the issue
of social fairness in the determination of the sizes of national CAP envelopes. The
calculations of political rents show that historical payments are neither a rational
nor a just solution, because the structurally low profitability of agriculture in certain
countries should be compensated for by a higher supply of public goods, and this
is not happening. Perhaps countries with structurally inefficient agriculture should
supply more public goods than they do at present, if they wish to maintain their
current ratio of political rents to gross added value, or else subsidise their agriculture
to a greater degree out of national funds.
Part 4 of the book contains case studies. These demonstrate the applicative
dimension of the paradigm of sustainable development and methods of evaluating
the effectiveness of agricultural policy in supporting such development in rural
areas. Naturally, the results of these studies are not representative for agriculture
as a whole (at national or EU level). Nonetheless, they indicate a direction for
discussion concerning the development of sustainable agriculture in theory and in
practice, and provide methodological guidance. They develop a methodology for
examining regional sustainable development, which enables not only a sustainability
assessment, but also a comparison of synthetic indicators over the whole of the
analysed period. Also a set of analytical models is proposed, which make possible
not only a better management of human and material capital in firms in agricultural
and food sectors, but also the identification of areas that need to be improved to
enable these resources to be used more competitively. Among the detailed findings,
the following are particularly striking:
• The location-specific factor “type of rural area”, based on land functions, is of
key importance for land value in the SAPS. The area type determines whether
particular use values, such as area or shape coefficient, and amenities, such
as the possibility of building, as well as payments under agricultural policy,
affect the land price.
• There is a very large variation in land prices in the SAPS, and prices are
strongly affected by speculation, which has driven the upward trend since the
introduction of area payments in 2004. However, the impact of speculation is
relatively small in areas with agrotouristic features.
• Agricultural policy, in particular payments for public goods, has a very large
significance (marginal effects) for the value of agricultural land compared
with other parcel-level attributes of properties.
• Payments for public goods are however capitalised in land prices only in
peripheral areas. Elsewhere they fail to perform their role, and are even
associated with the decapitalisation of the value of land. In particular, in
244 Summary: Political Rents and the European Model of Agriculture
agrotouristic areas these schemes should be complementary and not substitutive
with respect to the multifunctional development of the countryside. Therefore,
in most places at present, single area payment support is not a differentiating
factor for land value, in view of its general availability and low requirements,
and the other payments do not compensate for the opportunity costs related
to alternative ways of deriving rent from land.
• Similarly, support for agrotouristic activity did not have a significant effect
on the level of income from agrotourism among the analysed farms. This
was because interest in such support came from those farms that did not yet
obtain relatively high amounts of income from agrotourism; and moreover
the instrument was not of a universal nature, but required the fulfilment
of specified conditions. It can be expected that the situation was similar
throughout Poland.
• The relationships between agriculture and agrotourism are symbiotic in
nature. Their common plane includes both the income of farms engaged
in agricultural and agrotouristic activity, and the support provided by CAP
instruments. In consequence, the preliminary conclusion can be reached that
direct subsidies favour the economic activation of farms in non-agricultural
activity.
• The instruments of the CAP can be expected to evolve to favour the creation
of public goods at local authority level rather than the development of
agrotouristic activity itself at farm level.
A particularly striking aspect of the findings of these case studies is that they
point towards a common problem: the idea of payments for public goods under
agricultural policy is set forth as a leitmotif of the European agricultural model, but
in practice the CAP does not succeed in valuing these goods accurately. Perhaps this
value is too low compared with the funds allocated indirectly to support production
and efficiency, perversely given the name “decoupled”? Hence, the idea remains
more a declaration than reality. This conclusion is confirmed by the variation in
pure political rents obtained by agriculture (one might say non-equivalent rents)
between EU countries in 2004-2012: ranging from approximately 9% of value added
by agriculture in the Netherlands, to over 95% in Ireland. Are such disproportions,
which it is hard to justify by any objective criteria, acceptable from the point of
view of social justice and common community ideology? Alluding to the hypothesis
put forward at the outset: there is something called the European model for the
development of agriculture, but it is implemented in a minority of EU countries.
Their common denominator is that pure political rent, after taking account of public
goods and market corrections, accounts for a similar proportion of agricultural
income.
Collections
- Artykuły / Articles [15591]